When the French nobleman Alexis de Tocqueville toured the
newly founded American republic in the early years of the nineteenth century,
he encountered plenty of things that left him scratching his head. The national
obsession with making money, the atrocious food, and the weird way that high
culture found its way into the most isolated backwoods settings—“There is
hardly a pioneer's hut which does not contain a few odd volumes of Shakespeare,” he wrote; “I remember reading
the feudal drama of Henry V for the first time in a log cabin”—all intrigued
him, and found their way into the pages of his remarkable book
Democracy in America.
Still, one of the things de Tocqueville found most
astonishing bears directly on the theme I’ve been developing over the last
several weeks here on The Archdruid Report. The Americans of his time, when they wanted
to make something happen, didn’t march around with placards or write their legislators
demanding that the government do it.
Instead, far more often than not, they simply put together a private
association for the purpose, and did it themselves. De Tocqueville wrote:
“Americans combine to give fĂȘtes, found seminaries, build
churches, distribute books, and send missionaries to the antipodes. Hospitals,
prisons, and schools take shape in that way. Finally, if they want to proclaim
a truth or propagate some feeling by the encouragement of a great example, they
form an association. In every case, at the head of any new undertaking, where
in France you would find the government or in England some territorial magnate,
in the United States you are sure to find an association. I have come across
several types of association in America of which, I confess, I had not
previously the slightest conception, and I have often admired the extreme skill
they show in proposing a common object for the exertions of very many and in
inducing them voluntarily to pursue it.”
The types of associations de Tocqueville encountered used an
assortment of ingenious legal structures borrowed, for the most part, from
English common law. Those of my readers
who dislike the role of corporations in contemporary American life may be
interested to know that the distant and much less toxic ancestor of today’s
corporate structure was one of them. A corporation, back in those days, was not
a privileged legal pseudoperson with more rights and fewer responsibilities
than a human being. It was simply a
group of people who set out to accomplish some purpose, and got a charter from
the state government allowing them to raise money for that purpose by selling
shares of stock. Most had single
purposes—building a hospital, say, or a canal—and limited lifespans, defined
either as a fixed number of years or until the purpose of the corporation was
completed.
Making money was sometimes an object in such exercises, but
by no means always. Members of a local religious community who wanted to build
a new church, for example, would very often do that by organizing a corporation
to raise money for the construction costs.
Each member would buy as many shares as he or she could afford, and
fellow believers in neighboring towns who wanted to support the project might
also buy shares to chip in. When the
church was finished, the corporation would be wound up, and thereafter a
portion of the income from tithes and donations might be set apart to buy back
the shares a few at a time; on the other hand, the members of the congregation
might consider themselves well repaid when they filed into a new building on
Sunday mornings. It was a remarkably effective means of local microfinance, and
it paid for a huge number of civic improvements and public amenities in the
young republic.
Not all associations that directed their efforts toward the
public good in this way were corporations, and I hope I may be allowed a
personal reminiscence about one of the others.
I think most of my regular readers know that I’m a Freemason. Yes, I’m
quite aware that this makes me an object of vilification across most of the
further reaches of contemporary American political life; no, I don’t
particularly care, though it tickles my sense of absurdity to be accused to my
face now and then of being one of the evil space lizards David Icke rants about
in his books. In the town where I live, the various Masonic bodies meet in a
large and lovely century-old building—which was, by the way, constructed by the
sort of building corporation described earlier in this essay—and share certain
projects in common. This year, I serve as the secretary to one of those, the
Masonic Endowment Fund. Half a century ago, it had a different and more
revealing name: the Masonic Relief Fund.
Here’s how it functioned back in the day. Donations from
living members, bequests from dead ones, and a variety of fundraising
activities kept the Fund supplied with money, which it invested, and the
interest from those investments went to help Masonic brothers and their
families who fell onto hard times. The
members of the Relief Board, who were appointed by each lodge or other Masonic
body, investigated each case and then started writing checks.
Elderly brethren still recall the days when a long hard
winter meant that the poorer families in town would run out of money for coal
well before spring, and those who had a family member in the Masons could count
on the truck from the local coal firm making a delivery anyway. Groceries, visiting nurse services, school
expenses, funeral costs—the Relief Fund covered all those and much more. Everyone in the local Masonic scene supported
the project to whatever extent their means allowed. Partly that was because that’s what you do
when you’re a Freemason, and partly it was because everyone knew that, however
well off they were at the moment, some unexpected turn of events might leave
them in a situation where they had to rely on the Fund for their own survival.
The Fund no longer buys truckloads of coal for poor Masonic
families in the winter, and the reason for that is a microcosm of the impact of
empire on American communities. In the wake of Lyndon Johnson’s “Great Society”
programs of the 1960s, government welfare programs took the place of the
Masonic Relief Fund and its many equivalents in the lives of the local
poor. Requests for help slowed and then
stopped, and the Relief Board found itself sitting on an increasing pile of
money that no one seemed to need any more. After much discussion, and by vote
of the Masonic bodies that funded the Board, its name was changed to the
Masonic Endowment Fund and its income was put to work paying for improvements
on an aging Masonic building.
The same thing, often in much more drastic terms, happened
to many other voluntary organizations that once occupied the roles currently
more or less filled by government social welfare programs. In 1920, for
example, something like 3500 different fraternal orders existed in the United
States, and around 50% of the country’s adult population—counting both genders
and all ethnic groups, by the way—belonged to at least one of them. Reasons for
belonging ranged across the whole spectrum of human social phenomena, but there
were hard pragmatic reasons to put in a petition for membership at your local
lodge of the Odd Fellows, Knights of Pythias, or what have you: at a time when employers generally didn’t
provide sick pay and other benefits for employees, most fraternal orders did.
If you belonged to the Odd Fellows, for example, you went to
lodge one evening a week and paid your weekly dues, which were generally around
25 cents—that is, about the equivalent of a $20 bill today. In exchange, if you
became too sick to work, the lodge would give you sick pay, and if you died,
the lodge would cover the costs of your funeral and guarantee that your family
would be taken care of. If, as often happened,
the husband belonged to the Odd Fellows and the wife to the Rebekahs, the
women’s branch of the same organization, the family had a double claim on the
order’s help.
Here again, I can call on something more personal than the
abstract facts that can be gotten from old history books. My paternal
grandfather’s father was a city police officer in the wide-open port town of
Aberdeen, Washington, and an Odd Fellow.
In 1920 he was shot to death in the line of duty, leaving a wife and
thirteen children. The Aberdeen Odd Fellows lodge paid for his funeral and then
took care of his family—his children until they reached adulthood, his widow
for the rest of her life. It’s not an accident that my grandfather, when he was
in his twenties, became a founding member of a community service organization,
Active 20-30 International.
In 1920, Odd Fellowship was at the peak of its size and
influence, and ranked as the largest fraternal organization in North
America. Today, it’s a faint and
flickering shadow of its former self.
When welfare programs and employer-paid pensions came in, the core
function of the Odd Fellows and a great many organizations like it went out by
the same door. So, in due time, did most
of the organizations. We once had a thriving Odd Fellows lodge here in
Cumberland; the building is still there, with the letters IOOF in mosaic work
on the front step, but the lodge is long gone.
Now it’s only fair to point out that the shift from private
relief funds to government welfare programs had certain definite advantages.
The voluntary associations that handled relief in the pre-welfare era—fraternal
orders such as the Freemasons and Odd Fellows, religious bodies such as
churches and synagogues, and the like—had limited resources, and usually conserved
them by limiting their relief payments to their members, or to other narrowly
defined populations. To return to a
point made earlier in these posts, the relief organizations of an earlier day
had to treat their resources as a commons that could be destroyed by abuse, and
so they put a variety of limits on access to those resources to make sure that
the people who got help actually needed it, and weren’t simply trying to game
the system.
The deep pockets of government in an era of national expansion made it
possible, for a while, to ignore such factors.
The new social welfare programs could reach out to everyone who needed
them, or at least to everyone whose claim to need them advanced the agenda of
one political faction or another. The
resulting largesse was distributed in various amounts all over the class
spectrum—welfare for the poor, a dizzying array of direct and indirect federal
subsidies for the middle class, ample tax loopholes and corporate handouts to
benefit the rich—and did a great deal to fund the lavish lifestyles Americans
by and large enjoyed during their nation’s imperial zenith.
That’s the kind of thing a society can do when it can draw
on half a billion years of stored sunlight to prop up its economy, not to
mention a global empire that gives it privileged access to the energy, raw
materials, and products of industry that a half a billion years of stored
sunlight made possible. Whether or not it was a good idea isn’t a question I
particularly want to discuss at this point. It’s far more important, it seems
to me, to recognize that the welfare states of the late 20th century were the
product of a vast but temporary abundance of energy and the products of energy;
they did not exist before that glut of energy arrived, and it’s thus a safe bet
that they won’t exist after the glut is gone.
I think it’s at least as safe a bet, mind you, that nobody
in America will be willing to face that fact until long after the abundance of
the recent past is a fading memory. The
last decade or so of bickering in Washington DC is more than adequate evidence
of the way the winds are blowing. Republicans talk about jobs, Democrats talk
about justice, but in both cases what’s going on is best described as a
bare-knuckle brawl over which party’s voting blocs get to keep their accustomed
access to the federal feeding trough. Choose any point on the convoluted
political landscape of modern America, and the people at that position eagerly
criticize those handouts that don’t benefit them, but scream like irate
wildcats if anything threatens their own access to government largesse.
I suspect, for what it’s worth, that the last US government
handouts to be paid out will be those that prop up the lifestyles of the
American middle class: the financial aid that keeps middle class families from
having to shoulder the whole cost of a college education for their children,
the social security and medicare that keeps them from having to foot the whole
bill for their old age and that of their parents, the galaxy of programs
intended to make it easier for them to afford homeownership, and all the rest
of it. Programs that benefit the middle class disproportionately already make
up the largest share of US federal entitlement programs, dwarfing the 2% or so
of the federal budget that goes to the poor, or the 5% or so that counts as
corporate welfare, and that figure is a fair measure of the political clout the
middle class can wield in defense of its privileges.
It would be pleasant to suppose, as the United States slides
down the trajectory of imperial decline and the number of Americans in serious
trouble increases, that middle class voters would recognize the severity of the
situation and support, say, means tests on middle-class welfare programs, so
that those who don’t actually need help can be asked to step aside in favor of
those who do. I hope none of my readers plan on holding their breath and
waiting for this to happen, though. Quite the contrary: as economic contraction accelerates and
energy and resource shortages bite harder, the fight around the feeding trough
will just get worse. I doubt many of the combatants will take enough time from
the struggle to notice that, in the long run, it’s a fight with no winners.
In the time of limits ahead of us, no country on earth will
be able to afford a welfare state of the kind that was common in industrial
societies over the last century or so. That’s one of the harsh realities of our
predicament. National economies powered
by diffuse renewable energy sources, bound by strict ecological limits, and
forced to cope with the cascading instabilities of a damaged planetary
biosphere, simply won’t be able to produce the surplus wealth needed to make
that a possibility. Methods of providing for urgent social needs that worked in
the days before the economy of abundance are another matter, and for this
reason it makes sense to suggest a revival of the old American custom of
forming voluntary associations to fund and manage public amenities.
There are at least two important advantages to such a
project, and both of them take the form of lessons that Americans once knew and
are going to have to learn again in a hurry. The first is that a private
association doesn’t have the luxury of pretending that it has limitless
resources. Currently some 60% of
Americans receive more in the way of financial benefits from government than
they pay in taxes. Conservative pundits
like to insist that this means the well-to-do are getting robbed by taxation,
but the facts of the matter are considerably more troubling: the gap in
question is being covered with borrowed money—which means, in an era of
quantitative easing, that it’s being paid by printing money. That’s a recipe for massive economic trouble
in the short term. A private association, by contrast, can’t print its own
money, and if its members vote themselves more benefits than the treasury can
pay for, they will discover promptly enough why this isn’t a good idea.
That’s the first advantage. The second is closely related to
it. The benefit funds of the old
fraternal orders and their equivalents across the spectrum of voluntary
associations learned two crucial lessons very early on. The first was that some people are solely
interested in gaming the system for whatever they can get out of it, and are
unwilling to contribute anything in return.
The second is that allowing such people to get their way, and drain the
fund of its resources, is a fast road to failure. The standard response was to
limit access to the benefit fund to those who had contributed to it, or the
organization that sponsored it, at least to the extent of joining the
organization and keeping current on their dues.
That’s why the Masonic Relief Fund here in Cumberland only
bought coal for those poor families who had a family member in Freemasonry, and
why so many of the comparable funds operated by other lodges, by churches, and
by a range of other social institutions in the pre-welfare days had similar
rules. The reasoning involved in this
custom is the same logic of the commons we’ve discussed several times already
in this series of posts. A relief fund is a commons; like any other commons it
can be destroyed if those who have access to it are allowed to abuse it for
their own benefit; to prevent that from happening, limits on access to the
commons are essential.
There were also organizations that existed to provide help
to people other than their own members, and in fact most of the old lodges
directed some part of their efforts to helping people in the community at
large—as indeed most of them still do.
Here again, though, access to the limited resources that were available
was controlled, so that those resources could be directed where, in the best
judgment of the sponsoring organization, they would do the most good. Nineteenth-century talk about “the deserving
poor”—that is, those whose poverty was not primarily the result of their own
choices and habits, and who thus might well be able to better their conditions
given some initial help—is deeply offensive to many people in our present
culture of entitlement, but it reflects a hard reality.
Whether the habit of throwing money at the poor en masse is
a useful response to poverty or not, the fact remains that a post-imperial
America on the downslope of the age of cheap energy won’t have the resources to
maintain that habit even with the poor it’s already got, much less the vastly
increased numbers of the newly poor we’ll have as what’s left of our economy
winds down. Those who worry about ending
up destitute as that process unfolds need to be aware that they won’t be able
to turn to the government for help, and those whose sense of compassion leads
them to want to do something helpful for the poor might want to consider some
less futile response than trying to pry loose government funds for that
purpose.